首页
登录
职称英语
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased producti
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased producti
游客
2024-08-08
12
管理
问题
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased productivity led to decreases in working hours. Employees who had been putting in 12-hour days, six days a week, found their time on the job shrinking to 10 hours daily, then, finally, to eight hours, five days a week. Only a generation ago social planners worried about what people would do with all this new-found free time. In the U. S. , at least, it seems they need not have bothered.
Although the output per hour of work has more than doubled since 1945, leisure seems reserved largely for the unemployed and underemployed. Those who work full-time spend as much time on the job as they did at the end of World War II. In fact, working hours have increased noticeably since 1970--perhaps because real wages have stagnated since that year. Bookstores now abound with manuals describing how to manage time and cope with stress.
There are several reasons for lost leisure. Since 1979, companies have responded to improvements in the business climate by having employees work overtime rather than by hiring extra personnel, says economist Juliet B. Schor of Harvard University. Indeed, the current economic recovery has gained a certain amount of notoriety for its "jobless" nature: increased production has been almost entirely decoupled from employment. Some firms are even downsizing as their profits climb. "All things being equal, we’d be better off spreading around the work, " observes labour economist Ronald G. Ehrenberg of Cornell University.
Yet a host of factors pushes employers to hire fewer workers for more hours and, at the same time, compels workers to spend more time on the job. Most of those incentives involve what Ehrenberg calls the structure of compensation: quirks in the way salaries and benefits are organised that make it more profitable to ask 40 employees to labour an extra hour each than to hire one more worker to do the same 40-hour job.
Professional and managerial employees supply the most obvious lesson along these lines. Once people are on salary, their cost to a firm is the same whether they spend 35 hours a week in the office or 70. Diminishing returns may eventually set in as overworked employees lose efficiency or leave for more arable pastures. But in the short run, the employer’s incentive is clear.
Even hourly employees receive benefits--such as pension contributions and medical insurance-that are not tied to the number of hours they work. Therefore, it is more profitable for employers to work their existing employees harder.
For all that employees complain about long hours, they, too, have reasons not to trade money for leisure. "People who work reduced hours pay a huge penalty in career terms," Schor maintains. "It’s taken as a negative signal about their commitment to the firm. " [Lotte] Bailyn [of Massachusetts Institute of Technology] adds that many corporate managers find it difficult to measure the contribution of their underlings to a firm’s wellbeing, so they use the number of hours worked as a proxy for output. "Employees know this," she says, and they adjust their behavior accordingly.
"Although the image of the good worker is the one whose life belongs to the company," Bailyn says, "it doesn’t fit the facts. " She cites both quantitative and qualitative studies that show increased productivity for part-time workers: they make better use of the time they have, and they are less likely to succumb to fatigue in stressful jobs. Companies that employ more workers for less time also gain from the resulting redundancy, she asserts. "The extra people can cover the contingencies that you know are going to happen, such as when crises take people away from the workplace. " Positive experiences with reduced hours have begun to change the more-is-better culture at some companies, Schor reports.
Larger firms, in particular, appear to be more willing to experiment with flexible working arrangements...
It may take even more than changes in the financial and cultural structures of employment for workers successfully to trade increased productivity and money for leisure time, Schor contends. She says the U. S. market for goods has become skewed by the assumption of full-time, two-career households. Automobile makers no longer manufacture cheap models, and developers do not build the tiny bungalows that served the first postwar generation of home buyers. Not even the humblest household object is made without a microprocessor. As Schor notes, the situation is a curious inversion of the "appropriate technology" vision that designers have had for developing countries: U. S. goods are appropriate only for high incomes and long hours. [br] Social planners have been consulted about U. S. employment figures.
选项
A、Y
B、N
C、NG
答案
C
解析
该陈述文中并没有提到。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3710437.html
相关试题推荐
______isanaccentthatemergedatthebeginningofthenineteenthcentury,asso
JamesJoycerevolutionizedthenovel,theshortstory,andmodernliterature
JamesJoycerevolutionizedthenovel,theshortstory,andmodernliterature
FastBAA’sHeathrowExpressistherevolutionarynon-stoptrainservicethat
FastBAA’sHeathrowExpressistherevolutionarynon-stoptrainservicethat
Themid-and-late19thcenturyisgenerallyknownastheVictorianage,contro
Themid-and-late19thcenturyisgenerallyknownastheVictorianage,contro
Themid-and-late19thcenturyisgenerallyknownastheVictorianage,contro
Themid-and-late19thcenturyisgenerallyknownastheVictorianage,contro
Themid-and-late19thcenturyisgenerallyknownastheVictorianage,contro
随机试题
Overthepastdecade,Americancompanieshavetriedhardtofindwaystodis
集中火灾报警控制器的历史记录,包括火警记录、设备故障记录、请求记录、启动记录、反
考来替泊的降脂作用机制主要是A.抑制肝脏胆固醇转化 B.阻滞胆汁酸在肠道的重吸
循行至第3趾的经脉是A.足少阳胆经 B.足太阳膀胱经 C.足阳明胃经 D.
私募基金管理人自行销售私募基金的,风险揭示书由()签字确认。A.基金管理人
可以对过细的劳动分工进行改进的方法包括( )。A.交叉作业法 B.充实业
A.截面D位移为0 B. C. D.
甲市公安机关在侦办一起电信诈骗案件时,获取了犯罪嫌疑人在本市三个相邻区使用过的一
患者2周前因龋洞在外院做银汞合金充填。术后遇冷敏感症状加重,叩痛(+),近日有阵
评标时按事先公布的标准对所有投标文件进行评审,这属于招标投标要求遵循的( )原则
最新回复
(
0
)