首页
登录
职称英语
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea,
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea,
游客
2023-11-28
21
管理
问题
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea, yet many are unhygienic, self-absorbed , disconcertingly attached to ex-fish, or fans of Donald Trump. Digital dating sites, including a growing array of matchmaking apps, are meant to help. Their design owes more to hard-nosed economics than it does to the mysteries of the heart.
(2) In a sense, searching for a mate is not so different from hunting for a job. Jobs, like prospective partners, have their strengths and weaknesses, which makes finding the right one a matter of complicated tradeoffs. Such exchanges are different from other transactions, in that both parties must be enthusiastic about the match for it to happen. A supermarket, in contrast, does not particularly care whose wallet it is draining, nor does the power company agonise about whether a customer is worthy of its watts.
(3) Alvin Roth, who won a Nobel prize in economics for his work on market design, made a career of studying such "matching markets" , where supply and demand are not balanced by price. Instead, people transact based on information. An apple-seller can nudge down his prices until the whole cart is sold. Yet if Apple were looking to hire two workers, it would not set a salary so puny that only two people applied. The quality of new hires often matters at least as much as their salaries.
(4) Mr. Roth, who won the prize jointly with Lloyd Shapley in 2012, found that the structure of matching markets made a significant difference in determining who wound up with whom. Systems designed to elicit people’s true preferences generated better matches between hospitals and doctors, for example. But the entire medical profession has an interest in improving matches, and so can set up a national clearing house (信息搜集所) to do just that. The lovelorn (失恋的) must instead rely on an array of digital matchmakers.
(5) Good matches depend on good information. Even without digital help, people usually have some inkling of how much they have in common. Cosmopolitan strivers move to New York, say, rather than sleepier cities, in part because they will meet other ambitious types with similar interests. Within New York, the places people choose to spend their time—whether Yankee Stadium or a yoga studio—determine which sorts of people they come into contact with. Because it is expensive to live in New York, and to spend time sweating in a yoga studio or swearing in the stands, people in such settings cah be reasonably confident those around them are in some sense like-minded.
(6) But one critical bit of information is missing: whether there is mutual interest. The act of asking someone out is fraught. In the non-digital world, approaching a potential partner brings the risk of awkwardness or humiliation. Digital dating reduces this cost dramatically. Apps like Tinder and Happn, for example, reveal that a user likes another only when the feeling is mutual.
(7) The best matching markets are those that are " thick" , with lots of participants. The more people there are seeking digital dates, the greater the chance of finding a good match. Odds improve that another person in the crowd also enjoys Wagner, Thai food, or discussions about the economics of matching markets.
(8) The wealth of information many dating sites request may help to home in on the perfect match, but if the effort involved is enough to deter potential mates from joining in the first place, then it does more harm than good. When Tinder first launched, largely to facilitate casual sex, users assessed one another based only on looks, age and gender. Simplicity worked wonders; there are 26m matches made between Tinder users each day.
(9) The advantages of thick markets are lost, however, if they become too "congested", with users overwhelmed by the number of participants and unable to locate a good match among them. One response is to specialise. JSwipe, for instance, caters to Jewish singles while Bumble, an app where women must initiate contact, is meant to attract feminists.
(10) But the most popular apps seek to help their users filter possible mates using clever technology. Tinder, for example, only provides users with profiles of fellow Tinderites who are nearby, to make it that much easier to meet in person. It has also introduced a "super like" feature, which can be deployed only once a day, to allow smitten users to signal heightened interest in someone. In addition, last year it started allowing people to list their jobs and education, to help users to sort through the crowds. Users get the benefits both of a big pool of potential partners and various tools to winnow them.
Sex and the city
(11) The emergence of matching apps, for those seeking love or theatre tickets or a lift, has certainly made once-onerous tasks more convenient. They may also contribute to more profound economic change. Dating apps could strengthen the trend toward " assortative mating (造型交配)" , whereby people choose to couple with those of similar income and skills. By one estimate, the trend accounts for about 18% of the rise in income inequality in America between 1960 and 2005. A recent study of online dating in South Korea found that it boosted sorting among couples by education.
(12) Better matching may also mean bigger cities. Metropolitan goliaths have long been melting-pots, within which those early on in their adult lives link up with jobs, friends and mates. Matching apps, romantic or not, make it easier to navigate the urban sprawl and sample all it has to offer. That, in turn, should make the biggest cities relatively more attractive to young people.
(13) Apps cannot yet make break-ups less painful. And love remains mysterious enough that even the most refined algorithms (算法) cannot predict mutual attraction with confidence. But they clearly help, judging by their legions of users. After all, it is better to have super-liked and lost than never to have super-liked at all. [br] It can be inferred from the passage that Tinder’s users______.
选项
A、only take a fancy to candidates with mutual feeling
B、evaluate candidates both from outward traits and inner characters
C、can initiate contact on condition that they are female
D、cannot get the profiles of users living in another city
答案
D
解析
推断题。作者在第十段第二句提到Tinder只给用户提供附近用户的档案,由此可以推断,Tinder用户不可能得到居住在另外一个城市的用户的档案,故[D]为正确答案。第六段最后一句提到像Tinder和Happn这样的应用软件揭示了只有心意相通时,一个用户才会喜欢上另一个用户,[A]“Tinder用户只会喜欢上拥有相同感觉的候选对象”在原文直接提及,无需推断,故排除;第八段第二句提到当Tinder首次上线时,主要是为了方便随意性行为,用户们只根据外貌、年龄和性别来评估对方,由此可知,Tinder用户是只依据外在特征来评估候选对象,而不是根据外在特征和内在性格两方面,故排除[B];第九段最后一句指出必须由女性先主动联系的应用软件是Bumble,而不是Tinder,故排除[C]。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3227416.html
相关试题推荐
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
Acustomized,constantly-updatingnewspaperusedtobethestuffofscience
(1)Datingisatreacherousbusiness.Theremaybeplentyoffishinthesea,
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
随机试题
[originaltext]DeepSpringsisanAmericancollege.Itisanunusualcollege
()不属于制定预算过程的输出。A:成本基准 B:范围基准 C:项目资金需求
患者,男性,67岁,腹泻与便秘交替发生6个月。近3个月来腹部隐痛,近3天解鲜血便
A.木桂花B.凤眼草C.紫草D.大黄E.丹参含有蒽醌类化合物的是
关于风湿病的治疗,正确的是( )。A.一旦确诊应早期治疗 B.糖皮质激素的作
在证券组合中使基本收入与资本增长之间达到某种均衡的方法有()。 A.使组合中
发行人及其主承销商应当根据发行规模和市场情况,合理设定单一网上申购账户的申购上限
案例九:一般资料。求助者,女性,20岁,某大学二年级学生。 案例介绍:求助者从
投资项目决策分析与评价的基本要求包括贯彻落实科学发展观、资料数据准确可靠和()
患者男,67岁。知识分子,医生以肺部肿物待查收入院。住院后,确诊为肺癌,但尚未告
最新回复
(
0
)