首页
登录
职称英语
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased producti
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased producti
游客
2023-10-14
29
管理
问题
For the first century or so of the industrial revolution, increased productivity led to decreases in working hours. Employees who had been putting in 12-hour days, six days a week, found their time on the job shrinking to 10 hours daily, then, finally, to eight hours, five days a week. Only a generation ago social planners worried about what people would do with all this new-found free time. In the U. S. , at least, it seems they need not have bothered.
Although the output per hour of work has more than doubled since 1945, leisure seems reserved largely for the unemployed and underemployed. Those who work full-time spend as much time on the job as they did at the end of World War II. In fact, working hours have increased noticeably since 1970--perhaps because real wages have stagnated since that year. Bookstores now abound with manuals describing how to manage time and cope with stress.
There are several reasons for lost leisure. Since 1979, companies have responded to improvements in the business climate by having employees work overtime rather than by hiring extra personnel, says economist Juliet B. Schor of Harvard University. Indeed, the current economic recovery has gained a certain amount of notoriety for its "jobless" nature: increased production has been almost entirely decoupled from employment. Some firms are even downsizing as their profits climb. "All things being equal, we’d be better off spreading around the work, " observes labour economist Ronald G. Ehrenberg of Cornell University.
Yet a host of factors pushes employers to hire fewer workers for more hours and, at the same time, compels workers to spend more time on the job. Most of those incentives involve what Ehrenberg calls the structure of compensation: quirks in the way salaries and benefits are organised that make it more profitable to ask 40 employees to labour an extra hour each than to hire one more worker to do the same 40-hour job.
Professional and managerial employees supply the most obvious lesson along these lines. Once people are on salary, their cost to a firm is the same whether they spend 35 hours a week in the office or 70. Diminishing returns may eventually set in as overworked employees lose efficiency or leave for more arable pastures. But in the short run, the employer’s incentive is clear.
Even hourly employees receive benefits--such as pension contributions and medical insurance-that are not tied to the number of hours they work. Therefore, it is more profitable for employers to work their existing employees harder.
For all that employees complain about long hours, they, too, have reasons not to trade money for leisure. "People who work reduced hours pay a huge penalty in career terms," Schor maintains. "It’s taken as a negative signal about their commitment to the firm. " [Lotte] Bailyn [of Massachusetts Institute of Technology] adds that many corporate managers find it difficult to measure the contribution of their underlings to a firm’s wellbeing, so they use the number of hours worked as a proxy for output. "Employees know this," she says, and they adjust their behavior accordingly.
"Although the image of the good worker is the one whose life belongs to the company," Bailyn says, "it doesn’t fit the facts. " She cites both quantitative and qualitative studies that show increased productivity for part-time workers: they make better use of the time they have, and they are less likely to succumb to fatigue in stressful jobs. Companies that employ more workers for less time also gain from the resulting redundancy, she asserts. "The extra people can cover the contingencies that you know are going to happen, such as when crises take people away from the workplace. " Positive experiences with reduced hours have begun to change the more-is-better culture at some companies, Schor reports.
Larger firms, in particular, appear to be more willing to experiment with flexible working arrangements...
It may take even more than changes in the financial and cultural structures of employment for workers successfully to trade increased productivity and money for leisure time, Schor contends. She says the U. S. market for goods has become skewed by the assumption of full-time, two-career households. Automobile makers no longer manufacture cheap models, and developers do not build the tiny bungalows that served the first postwar generation of home buyers. Not even the humblest household object is made without a microprocessor. As Schor notes, the situation is a curious inversion of the "appropriate technology" vision that designers have had for developing countries: U. S. goods are appropriate only for high incomes and long hours. [br] During the industrial revolution people worked harder.
选项
A、Y
B、N
C、NG
答案
C
解析
文中并没有提及在工业革命期间,工人更加卖力的工作。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3095817.html
相关试题推荐
Theexhibition,entitled"WesternLandscapePaintingsfromthe16thCentury
Theexhibition,entitled"WesternLandscapePaintingsfromthe16thCentury
Theexhibition,entitled"WesternLandscapePaintingsfromthe16thCentury
Productionistobe______frombigcitiestothemountainousareasincaseofwar
WhatwillhappentotheHimalayanMountainsbytheendofthe21stcentury?[ori
OfallthemanyfactorswhichcontributedtotheIndustrialRevolution,
Productionistobe________frombigcitiestothemountainousareasincaseofw
PeopleintheUnitedStatesinthenineteenthcenturywerehauntedbythepr
PeopleintheUnitedStatesinthenineteenthcenturywerehauntedbythepr
PeopleintheUnitedStatesinthenineteenthcenturywerehauntedbythepr
随机试题
WhichofthefollowingisNOTanabbreviation?A、Prof.B、Gang.C、Ad.D、Fridge.B功
A.超静定三次 B.超静定六次 C.超静定九次 D.超静定十二次
A.成熟型囊性畸胎瘤 B.未成熟畸胎瘤 C.颗粒细胞瘤 D.无性细胞瘤
患者,40岁,血尿、蛋白尿5年,24h尿蛋白1.0~1.7g,血压150/90m
建筑高度也称为建筑总高度,是指()到建筑物屋面、檐口或女儿墙的高度。A.建筑
用计算机生成或打印的工作票应使用统一的票面格式,由()审核无误,手工或电子签名后
人在每一瞬间,将心理活动选择了某些对象而忽略了另一些对象。这一特点指的是注意的(
社会主义市场经济体制的基础是( )。A、以间接手段为主的完善宏观调控体系 B、
根据《企业破产法》规定,下列关于管理人的说法错误的是()。A.管理人由人民法院指
2014-68.根据《中华人民共和国土地管理法》,国家编制土地利用总体规划,规定
最新回复
(
0
)