首页
登录
职称英语
(1)It’s a golden age for studying inequality. Thomas Piketty, a French econo
(1)It’s a golden age for studying inequality. Thomas Piketty, a French econo
游客
2024-11-14
8
管理
问题
(1)It’s a golden age for studying inequality. Thomas Piketty, a French economist, set the benchmark in 2014 when his book, "Capital in the Twenty-First Century", was published in English and became a bestseller. The book mapped the contours of the crisis with a sweeping theory of economic history. Inequality, which had been on the wane from the 1930s until the 1970s, had risen sharply back toward the high levels of the Industrial Revolution, he argued. Now Branko Milanovic, an economist at the Luxembourg Income Study Centre and the City University of New York, has written a comprehensive follow-up. It reinforces how Utile is really known about economic forces of long duration.
(2)In some ways "Global Inequality" is a less ambitious book than "Capital". It is shorter, and written more like an academic working paper than a work of substantial scholarship for a wider readership.
(3)Like Mr Piketty, he begins with piles of data assembled over years of research. He sets the trends of different individual countries in a global context. Over the past 30 years the incomes of workers in the middle of the global income distribution have soared, as has pay for the richest 1% . At the same time, incomes of the working class in advanced economies have stagnated. This dynamic helped create a global middle class. It also caused global economic inequality to plateau, and perhaps even decline, for the first time since industrialisation began.
(4)To help interpret these facts, Mr Milanovic provides the readers with a series of neat mental models. He muses, for instance, that at the dawn of industrialisation, inequality within countries(or class-based inequality)was responsible for the largest gaps between rich people and poor. After industrialisation, inequality across countries(or location-based inequality)became more important. But as gaps between countries become ever more narrow, class-based inequality will become more important as most of the differences in incomes between rich people and poor people will once again be due to gaps within countries. He seasons the discussion with interesting comments, such as how incomes and inequality fell over the course of the Roman Empire.
(5)Mr Milanovic’s boldest contribution is about "Kuznets waves", which he offers as an alternative to two other prevailing theories of inequality. Simon Kuznets, a 20th-century economist, argued that inequality is low at low levels of development, rises during industrialisation and falls as countries reach economic maturity: high inequality is the temporary side-effect of the developmental process. Mr Piketty offered an alternative explanation: that high levels of inequality are the natural state of modern economies. Only unusual events, like the two world wars and the Depression of the 1930s, disrupt that normal equilibrium.
(6)Mr Milanovic suggests that both are mistaken. Across history, he reckons, inequality has tended to flow in cycles: Kuznets waves. In the pre-industrial period, these waves were governed by Malthusian dynamics: inequality would rise as countries enjoyed a spell of good fortune and high incomes, then fall as war or famine dragged average income back to subsistence level. With industrialisation, the forces creating Kuznets waves changed: to technology, openness and policy(TOP, as he shortens it). In the 19th century technological advance, globalisation and policy shifts all worked together in mutually reinforcing ways to produce dramatic economic change. Workers were reallocated from farms to factories, average incomes and inequality soared and the world became unprecedentedly interconnected. Then a combination of forces, some malign(war and political upheaval)and some benign(increased education)squeezed inequality to the lows of the 1970s.
(7)Since then, the rich world has been riding a new Kuznets wave, propelled by another era of economic change. Technological progress and trade work together to squeeze workers, he says: cheap technology made in foreign economies undermines the bargaining power of rich-world workers directly, and makes it easier for firms to replace people with machines. Workers’ declining economic power is compounded by lost political power as the very rich use their fortunes to influence candidates and elections.
(8)This diagnosis carries with it a predictive element. Mr Milanovic expects rich-world inequality to keep rising, in America especially, before eventually declining. Importantly, he argues that the downswing in inequality that occurs on the backside of a Kuznets wave is an inevitable result of the preceding rise. Where Mr Piketty sees the inequality-compressing historical events of the early 20th century as an accident, Mr Milanovic believes them to be the direct result of soaring inequality. The search for foreign investment opportunities engendered imperialism and set the stage for war. There are parallels, if imperfect ones, to the modern economy: rich economies seem to be stagnating as the very rich struggle to find places to earn good returns on their piles of wealth.
(9)Mr Milanovic’s analysis leads him to consider some dark possibilities as he looks ahead. America looks to be falling into the grips of an undemocratic plutocracy(富豪统治), he says, which is dependent on an expanding security state. In Europe right-wing nativism(本土主义)is on the rise. The good news is that emerging economies will probably continue on their path toward rich-world incomes—though that, he allows, is not guaranteed, and could be threatened by political crisis in other markets.
(10)The book’s conclusion is a little unsatisfying. A theory in which rising inequality eventually triggers countervailing social dislocations feels intuitively right, but it also leaves many important questions unanswered. When is war, rather than revolution, the probable outcome of inequality? Are governments at the mercy of the cycle, or can they act pre-emptively to flatten out the waves and avoid crises of high inequality? Mr Milanovic’s contributions are ultimately similar to those made by Mr Piketty. The data he provides offer a clearer picture of great economic puzzles, and his bold theorising chips away at tired economic orthodoxies. But the grand theory does as much to reveal the scale of contemporary ignorance as to illuminate the mechanics of the global economy. [br] According to Mr. Milanovic, the Kuznets wave in rich countries is currently governed by______.
选项
A、technological progress and trade
B、Malthusian dynamics
C、technology, openness and policy
D、big political changes and improved education
答案
A
解析
细节题。作者在第七段第一句中提到自上世纪70年代以来,富裕国家就一直处在新一轮的“库兹涅茨波浪”之上,并指出这新一轮的“库兹涅茨波浪”是由另一个经济变革时代所推动的,然后在第二句详细解释出现变化的是技术进步和贸易,因此[A]为答案。第六段第三句提到在前工业化时期,“库兹涅茨波浪”是由马尔萨斯动力学控制,故排除[B];第六段第四句指出在工业化时期,生成“库兹涅茨波浪”的力量是技术、开放和政策,第五句进一步强调在19世纪时,技术进步、全球化和政策转变以互相强化的方式共同发挥作用,从而导致巨大的经济变化,故排除[C]和[D]。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3844518.html
相关试题推荐
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
OnFeb.2,2007,theUnitedNationsscientificpanelstudyingclimatechang
OnFeb.2,2007,theUnitedNationsscientificpanelstudyingclimatechang
OnFeb.2,2007,theUnitedNationsscientificpanelstudyingclimatechang
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
(1)It’sagoldenageforstudyinginequality.ThomasPiketty,aFrenchecono
随机试题
龟tortoise
[originaltext]M:Hello,andwelcometoourprogram"WorkingAbroad".Ourguest
超高分子量聚乙烯(UHMWPE)管的许多性能是普通塑料管无法相比的,( )为塑
地形图上0.1mm的长度相应于地面的水平距离称为: A.比例尺B.数字比例
下列属于教学过程本质说的是()A.交往说 B.传递说 C.认识实践说 D
对照左边的图形,不能由它分割成的是()。
根据上表,长江流域河流湿地约占全部河流湿地面积的:() A.20% B.
召开股东大会的上市公司要提前()天刊登公告。 A.10B.15
以下两句来自人力资源部向各业务部门发送的人力需求通知: (1)为深入实施我行的
建设项目投产后对国民经济的净贡献包括( )。A.职工缴纳的社会保险 B.企业缴
最新回复
(
0
)