首页
登录
职称英语
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea,
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea,
游客
2024-11-12
3
管理
问题
(1) Dating is a treacherous business. There may be plenty of fish in the sea, yet many are unhygienic, self-absorbed , disconcertingly attached to ex-fish, or fans of Donald Trump. Digital dating sites, including a growing array of matchmaking apps, are meant to help. Their design owes more to hard-nosed economics than it does to the mysteries of the heart.
(2) In a sense, searching for a mate is not so different from hunting for a job. Jobs, like prospective partners, have their strengths and weaknesses, which makes finding the right one a matter of complicated tradeoffs. Such exchanges are different from other transactions, in that both parties must be enthusiastic about the match for it to happen. A supermarket, in contrast, does not particularly care whose wallet it is draining, nor does the power company agonise about whether a customer is worthy of its watts.
(3) Alvin Roth, who won a Nobel prize in economics for his work on market design, made a career of studying such "matching markets" , where supply and demand are not balanced by price. Instead, people transact based on information. An apple-seller can nudge down his prices until the whole cart is sold. Yet if Apple were looking to hire two workers, it would not set a salary so puny that only two people applied. The quality of new hires often matters at least as much as their salaries.
(4) Mr. Roth, who won the prize jointly with Lloyd Shapley in 2012, found that the structure of matching markets made a significant difference in determining who wound up with whom. Systems designed to elicit people’s true preferences generated better matches between hospitals and doctors, for example. But the entire medical profession has an interest in improving matches, and so can set up a national clearing house (信息搜集所) to do just that. The lovelorn (失恋的) must instead rely on an array of digital matchmakers.
(5) Good matches depend on good information. Even without digital help, people usually have some inkling of how much they have in common. Cosmopolitan strivers move to New York, say, rather than sleepier cities, in part because they will meet other ambitious types with similar interests. Within New York, the places people choose to spend their time—whether Yankee Stadium or a yoga studio—determine which sorts of people they come into contact with. Because it is expensive to live in New York, and to spend time sweating in a yoga studio or swearing in the stands, people in such settings cah be reasonably confident those around them are in some sense like-minded.
(6) But one critical bit of information is missing: whether there is mutual interest. The act of asking someone out is fraught. In the non-digital world, approaching a potential partner brings the risk of awkwardness or humiliation. Digital dating reduces this cost dramatically. Apps like Tinder and Happn, for example, reveal that a user likes another only when the feeling is mutual.
(7) The best matching markets are those that are " thick" , with lots of participants. The more people there are seeking digital dates, the greater the chance of finding a good match. Odds improve that another person in the crowd also enjoys Wagner, Thai food, or discussions about the economics of matching markets.
(8) The wealth of information many dating sites request may help to home in on the perfect match, but if the effort involved is enough to deter potential mates from joining in the first place, then it does more harm than good. When Tinder first launched, largely to facilitate casual sex, users assessed one another based only on looks, age and gender. Simplicity worked wonders; there are 26m matches made between Tinder users each day.
(9) The advantages of thick markets are lost, however, if they become too "congested", with users overwhelmed by the number of participants and unable to locate a good match among them. One response is to specialise. JSwipe, for instance, caters to Jewish singles while Bumble, an app where women must initiate contact, is meant to attract feminists.
(10) But the most popular apps seek to help their users filter possible mates using clever technology. Tinder, for example, only provides users with profiles of fellow Tinderites who are nearby, to make it that much easier to meet in person. It has also introduced a "super like" feature, which can be deployed only once a day, to allow smitten users to signal heightened interest in someone. In addition, last year it started allowing people to list their jobs and education, to help users to sort through the crowds. Users get the benefits both of a big pool of potential partners and various tools to winnow them.
Sex and the city
(11) The emergence of matching apps, for those seeking love or theatre tickets or a lift, has certainly made once-onerous tasks more convenient. They may also contribute to more profound economic change. Dating apps could strengthen the trend toward " assortative mating (造型交配)" , whereby people choose to couple with those of similar income and skills. By one estimate, the trend accounts for about 18% of the rise in income inequality in America between 1960 and 2005. A recent study of online dating in South Korea found that it boosted sorting among couples by education.
(12) Better matching may also mean bigger cities. Metropolitan goliaths have long been melting-pots, within which those early on in their adult lives link up with jobs, friends and mates. Matching apps, romantic or not, make it easier to navigate the urban sprawl and sample all it has to offer. That, in turn, should make the biggest cities relatively more attractive to young people.
(13) Apps cannot yet make break-ups less painful. And love remains mysterious enough that even the most refined algorithms (算法) cannot predict mutual attraction with confidence. But they clearly help, judging by their legions of users. After all, it is better to have super-liked and lost than never to have super-liked at all. [br] The word "ex-fish" in Para. 1 is used as a______.
选项
A、metaphor
B、metonymy
C、simile
D、personification
答案
B
解析
修辞题。文章第一段第二句句意为:也许天涯处处有芳草,但很多人都不讲卫生、自我沉醉、异常迷恋前任,或者是唐纳德-特朗普的粉丝。此处“fish”使用了修辞手法metonymy,用“鱼”来比喻“恋人”,该修辞手法只出现喻体,本体和比喻词都不出现,即直接把本体说成喻体,故[B]“转喻”为正确答案。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3841971.html
相关试题推荐
(1)Datingisatreacherousbusiness.Theremaybeplentyoffishinthesea,
(1)Datingisatreacherousbusiness.Theremaybeplentyoffishinthesea,
(1)Datingisatreacherousbusiness.Theremaybeplentyoffishinthesea,
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
[originaltext]W:Soundsgood.Thatkindofresponsibilitycanbeintimidatingi
(1)Whenitcomestoraisinggirls,today’smomshaveplentytoworryabout:
(1)Whenitcomestoraisinggirls,today’smomshaveplentytoworryabout:
随机试题
简述学科课程论的基本观点。
超声判断胎儿宫内生长迟缓的指标不包括以下哪一项A.双顶径 B.羊水 C.腹围
在进行针入度试验中,测定针入度值大于200的沥青试样时,至少用()标准针,
在以下菜系中,属于四大菜系的有()。A.鲁菜 B.闽菜 C.川菜 D.苏菜
工业生产用的管道防“跑、冒、滴、漏”属( )的质量范畴。 A、适用性
从所给的四个选项中,选择最合适的一个填入问号处,使之呈现一定的规律性:
用直线趋势法预测甲类房地产的价格变化趋势为V甲=1480+80i,乙类房地产价格
简述员工满意度调查的基本步骤。
透脓散的功用是A.活血祛瘀 B.祛瘀通络 C.托毒溃脓 D.化痰散结
关于舒张性心衰的治疗,下列哪项〒正确? A.受体阻滞剂B.洋地黄C.A
最新回复
(
0
)