首页
登录
职称英语
Passage Three (1) London may be Europe’s commercial capital, but not all
Passage Three (1) London may be Europe’s commercial capital, but not all
游客
2024-11-03
13
管理
问题
Passage Three
(1) London may be Europe’s commercial capital, but not all Britons are thrilled about that. In a poll conducted in 2014, two-thirds of non-Londoners reckoned that London had a positive impact on the British economy as a whole, but fewer than a third thought London’s strength was good for their city. London lures skilled workers and productive companies away from other parts of Britain. It also lures workers and firms from across Europe—something that makes many Britons, both in London and beyond, bristle. Indeed, London’s mop-topped (卷发的) mayor, Boris Johnson, this week joined the campaign to persuade Britons to withdraw from the European Union.
(2) London dominates Britain, accounting for 23% of its population and about a third of its economic output. The city grew to enormous size in the 19th and early 20th century, when it served as the political and economic hub of a global empire. The post-war decline in its population, a result both of the loss of empire and of policies intended to curb its growth, ended in the 1980s, when the globalisation of finance rejuvenated (复兴) the city’s main industry. Greater London is the fifth-largest metropolitan economy in the world, according to the Brookings Institution, a think-tank (智库). It is the EU’s largest city, by both population and output.
(3) Yet London should arguably be bigger than it is. It is Europe’s most important financial centre, and one of its biggest hubs for information industries and professional services— the European analogue to New York city. But London accounts for just 4. 5% of the EU’s output, after adjusting for variation in the cost of living, and just 2.9% of its population, whereas New York accounts for 8. 1% of America’s GDP and 6. 3% of its population. Were European integration ever to yield something like a United States of Europe (and Britain ever to be part of such an enterprise), London would probably swell in size and importance.
(4) Why should that be the case? Economists have touted the benefits of cities since 1826, when a German one named Johann Heinrich von Thiinen tried to explain why farmers gather in villages rather than living by their fields. Paul Krugman, in a paper published in 1991, homed in on the role of "increasing returns to scale" in driving the growth of cities. Because it is expensive to move people and goods, customers want to be where producers are and vice versa. As cities grow, increasing returns kick in: the more people who live in a particular place, the more attractive that place becomes to others. Mr. Krugman focused on clustering in manufacturing. Two trading regions with a slight imbalance in population would naturally evolve into a developed core and an underpopulated periphery, he argued. In the paper, which the Nobel committee cited when awarding him the prize for economics, Mr. Krugman pointed as an example to Europe, where industrial activity is concentrated in the north-west.
(5) Manufacturing no longer drives urbanisation in the rich world. In 2009 Edward Glaeser and Joshua Gottlieb of Harvard University surveyed recent research in order to distil the nature and causes of the " wealth of cities". Although manufacturing firms have grown less likely to concentrate together in dense areas, thanks to the falling cost and hassle of shipping, firms in knowledge-based industries like technology and finance have become more prone to clustering. In cities with lots of skilled workers, productivity tends to rise with population density. The authors reckon that it is now the advantage of associating with other clever people, and the intellectual stimulation and exchange that results, that gives the biggest cities their magnetism.
City sticker
(6) Congestion slows cities’ breakneck (极快的) growth: housing and transport infrastructure seldom keep pace with demand. As a result, rather than a single metropolitan goliath, economies tend to develop a series of cities distributed by size according to "Zipfs law" (named after George Zipf, an American linguist). The largest city tends to be twice the size of the second-largest, three times the size of the third-largest, and so on. American cities roughly follow this pattern. In the less-integrated EU, however, there is instead a jumble of big cities and a dearth (匮乏) of medium-sized ones.
(7) Deeper integration would push Europe toward a more American distribution. London would probably be the main beneficiary, given its particular strengths. Europe’s financial markets remain highly fragmented. Its stockmarkets are about half the size of America’s, despite the similar size of the two economies; European corporate-bond markets are about a third of the size. Few Italian firms, for instance, turn to their country’s relatively small equity or bond markets for funding. Instead, they simply borrow from Italian banks, which tend to have their headquarters in Milan. The EU is currently trying to rectify that by making it easier to borrow, lend and invest across its internal borders, in the hope of reducing funding costs for European firms. If such efforts bear fruit and Britain remains a part of the union, firms based in London would help more foreign companies issue shares or bonds there, at the expense of other European financial centres. Easing the cross-border provision of services, another thing on the EU’s long-term agenda, would likewise prove a boon for London.
(8) That prospect would naturally discomfit continentals. Just as New York rose head and shoulders above Philadelphia and Boston as the American economy grew and integrated, Paris, Frankfurt and Milan could all expect to cede ground to London in a close-knit EU. But London’s boosters might also blanch at the growth deeper integration might bring. It would mean more building, for starters. Greater London added 23,000 new housing units in the year to September, less than a third of the new units approved in New York last year. Were London to follow the example of New York, its GDP and population could eventually eclipse that of the rest of Britain, lengthening the political and cultural shadows cast across the rest of the country. Mr. Johnson is angling for a promotion to prime minister; ironically, a vote to remain could make his current job one of the most desirable in Europe. [br] The paper written by Paul Krugman claims all of the following EXCEPT________.
选项
A、why farmers prefer gathering in villages to living by fields
B、the role of increasing returns to scale in city development
C、how increasing returns begin as cities grow
D、clustering in manufacturing in the north-west of Europe
答案
A
解析
细节题。文章第四段第二句指出,解释为什么农民宁愿群居在村庄中也不愿住在田边的是一位名叫约翰.海因里希.冯.杜的德国人,而不是保罗.克鲁格曼,[A]与原文不符,故为本题答案。第三句提到在1991年发表的一篇论文中,保罗.克鲁格曼着重论述了“规模收益递增”在推动城市发展中的作用,故排除[B];第五句指出随着城市的发展,收益递增开始显现,故排除[C];该段最后一句提到在这篇诺贝尔奖评委会给克鲁格曼颁发经济学奖时所引用的论文中,他以工业活动集中在欧洲的西北部为例,故排除[D]。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3829582.html
相关试题推荐
SincethefoundationoftheCapitalLibraryAllianceinBeijing,34university
PassageThree[br]AccordingtoPara.5,whatareKoolhaasgloatingover?Peo
PassageTwo[br]WhatisPatel’sviewofOfqual’suseofdata?Itisnotsmar
PassageThree(1)RemKoolhaas,thePritzkerPrizewinningDutcharchite
PassageThree(1)RemKoolhaas,thePritzkerPrizewinningDutcharchite
PassageThree(1)RemKoolhaas,thePritzkerPrizewinningDutcharchite
PassageTwo(1)Resultsdayhasatime-wornrhythm,fullofannualtrope
PassageTwo(1)Resultsdayhasatime-wornrhythm,fullofannualtrope
PassageTwo(1)Resultsdayhasatime-wornrhythm,fullofannualtrope
PassageOne(1)"YouhavetoldBlank,andDash,andChoseaboutthema
随机试题
A、Thebankhasatendencytochoosemenastheiremployees.B、CVisimportantfo
Itisoftensaidthatpolitenesscostsnothing.Infact,itseemsthatalit
简述开展社区营养工作需要收集的资料。
A.EB病毒 B.乳头瘤病毒 C.乙型肝炎病毒 D.人类免疫缺陷(HIV)
从所给的四个选项中,选择最合适的一个填入问号处,使之呈现一定的规律性: A.如
“对自己感兴趣的问题总是刨根问底”这一典型表现所属的年龄段一般是()A.2~3
共用题干 某汽车客运站2012年3月运输统计数据如下:(1)全月计划班次为30
某银行的外汇买卖报价是AUD1=USD0.7462,USD1=SGD1.3524
一般情况下,会计制度健全的上市公司适用的税款征收方式是()。A.查账征收
关于留置的说法,正确的是( )。A.留置权可以通过合同的约定产生 B.留置权
最新回复
(
0
)