首页
登录
职称英语
Born in the trough of the Great Depression, Edmund Phelps, a professor at Col
Born in the trough of the Great Depression, Edmund Phelps, a professor at Col
游客
2023-12-15
23
管理
问题
Born in the trough of the Great Depression, Edmund Phelps, a professor at Columbia University who won the Nobel Prize for economics, has spent much of his intellectual life studying slumps of a different kind. The Depression, which cost both of his parents their jobs, was exacerbated by the monetary, authorities, who kept too tight a grip on the money supply. Mr. Phelps is interested in unemployment that even open-handed central bankers cannot cure.
Most scholars stand on the shoulders of giants. But Mr. Phelps won his laurels in part tar kicking the feet from under his intellectual forerunners. In 1958 William Phillips, of the London School of Economics, showed that for much of the previous hundred years, unemployment was low in Britain when wage inflation was high, and high when inflation was low. Economists were too quick to conclude that policy makers therefore faced a grand, macroeconomic trade-off, embodied in the so-called "Phillips curve". They could settle for unemployment of, say, 6% and an inflation rate of 1%—as prevailed in America at the start of the 1960s—or they could quicken the economy, cutting unemployment by a couple of percentage points at the expense of inflation of 3% or so—which is roughly how things stood in America when Mr. Phelps published his first paper on the subject in 1967.
In such a tight lab our market, companies appease workers by offering higher wages. They then pass on the cost in the form of dearer prices, cheating workers of a higher real wage. Thus policymakers can engineer lower unemployment only through deception. But "man is a thinking, expectant being,"as Mr. Phelps has put it. Eventually workers will cotton on, demanding still higher wages to offset the rising cost of living. They can be duped for as long as inflation stays one step ahead of their rising expectations of what it will be.
The stable trade-off depicted by the Phillips curve is thus a dangerous mirage. The economy will recover its equilibrium only when workers’ expectations are fulfilled, prices turn out as anticipated, and they no longer sell their labour under false pretences. But equilibrium does not, sadly, imply full employment. Mr. Phelps argued that inflation will not settle until unemployment rises to its "natural rate", leaving some workers moldering on the shelf. Given economists’ almost theological commitment to the notion that markets clear, the presence of unemployment in the world requires a theodicy to explain it. Mr. Phelps is willing to entertain several. But in much of his work he contends that unemployment is necessary to cow workers, ensuring their loyalty to the company and their diligence on the job, at a wage the company can afford to pay.
"Natural" does not mean optimal. Nor, Mr. Phelps has written, does it mean "a pristine element of nature not susceptible to intervention by man. " Natural simply means impervious to central bankers’ efforts to change it, how much money they print.
Economists, including some of his own students, commonly take this natural rate to be slow moving, if not constant, and devote a great deal of effort to estimating it. Mr. Phelps, by contrast, has been more anxious to explain its fluctuations, and to recommend measures to lower it. His book Structural Slumps, published in 1994, is an ambitious attempt to provide a general theory of how the natural rate of unemployment evolves. Some of the factors that he considered important--unemployment benefits or payroll taxes, for example—are widely accepted parts of the story. Others are more idiosyncratic. He and his French collaborator, Jean-Paul Fitoussi, have, for example, blamed Europe’s mounting unemployment in the 1980s in part on Ronald Reagan’s budget deficits, which were expansionary at home, but squeezed employment in the rest of the world.
A few years ago David Walsh, an economic journalist, lamented that the glare of the Nobel Prize left other equally deserving economists, such as Mr. Phelps, languishing "in the half-lit penumbra of the shortlist". After an unaccountably long lag, professional acclaim for this bold, purposeful theorist finally converged on its natural rate. [br] The phrase "cotton on" in Paragraph 3 probably means
选项
A、work on.
B、catch on.
C、call on.
D、make on.
答案
B
解析
语义题。本段第三句提到Thus policymakers can engineer lower unemployment only through deception,接着话锋一转,指出man is a thinking,expectant being,那么实现本句后面的demanding still higher wages to offset the rising cost of living的前提应该是他们知道自己受骗了,因此cotton on意为“理解”,即catch on,符合上下文语义衔接,[B]为答案。work on意为“继续工作”,与后面的demanding higher wages无关,排除;call on意为“号召”,这个短语后面应该跟宾语,即提出号召的对象,在这里不符合此处语义语法关系,故[C]排除;make on意为“在……上获利,在……上赚钱”,同样,这里也缺少宾语,故[D]排除。
转载请注明原文地址:https://tihaiku.com/zcyy/3275917.html
相关试题推荐
[originaltext]DianeLarsen-Freemanisawell-knownAmericanprofessorofapp
[originaltext]DianeLarsen-Freemanisawell-knownAmericanprofessorofapp
[originaltext]DianeLarsen-Freemanisawell-knownAmericanprofessorofapp
[originaltext]DianeLarsen-Freemanisawell-knownAmericanprofessorofapp
[originaltext]DianeLarsen-Freemanisawell-knownAmericanprofessorofapp
[originaltext]Host:Today,I’mveryhappytohaveprofessorPornchaiwithme.H
[originaltext]INTERVIEWER:ProfessorNadelmanne,youhavebeenoneoftheearli
[originaltext]INTERVIEWER:ProfessorNadelmanne,youhavebeenoneoftheearli
[originaltext]INTERVIEWER:ProfessorNadelmanne,youhavebeenoneoftheearli
[originaltext](knockonthedoor)Professor:Comein.Comein.Michael:Goodmo
随机试题
[originaltext]WOMAN:Goodafternoon,MrGray.Thanksforcomingtoouruniversi
TheDogwiththeGoldenNose[img]2016m3x/ct_eyyjsbz2011j
.与喉返神经伴行进入喉内的动脉是:()A.甲状腺上动脉 B.喉上动脉
典型的信息系统项目开发的过程中,()阶段拟定了系统的目标、范围和要求,而系
一般情况下不需要治疗的疾病是A.沟纹舌 B.白斑 C.创伤性溃疡 D.腺周
患者,女,28岁。跳舞时突感剧烈头痛,呕吐。查体:脑膜刺激征(+),无肢瘫。临床
个人转让自用5年以上,并且是家庭唯一生活用房取得的所得,个人所得税( )。A.
同业拆借是指商业银行()。A:从中央银行取得的资金 B:之间的临时性借款 C
关于岩体结构以下说法正确的有()。A.层状结构是较理想的各类工程岩体 B
下列灯光系统中用并联供电的是(??)。A.顺序闪光灯 B.泛光照明 C.跑道
最新回复
(
0
)