首页
登录
职称英语
Changes in the volume of unemployment are governed by three fundamental force
Changes in the volume of unemployment are governed by three fundamental force
游客
2025-04-13
28
管理
问题
Changes in the volume of unemployment are governed by three fundamental forces: the growth of the labor force, the increase in output per man hour, and the growth of total demand for goods and services. Changes in the average hours of work enter in exactly parallel fashion but have been quantitatively less significant. As productivity rises, less labor is required per dollar of national product, or more goods and services can be produced with the same number of man—goods.
If output does not grow, employment will certainly fall; if production increases more rapidly than productivity (less any decline in average hours worked, employment must rise. But the labor force grows, too. Unless gross national product (total final expenditure for goods and services corrected for price changes) rises more rapidly than the sum of productivity increase and labor force growth (again modified for any change in hours of work), the increase in employment will be inadequate to absorb the growth in the labor force. Inevitably the unemployment rate will increase. Only when total production expands faster than the rate of labor force growth plus the rate of productivity increase and minus the rate at which average annual hours fall does the unemployment fall. Increases in productivity were more important than growth of the labor force as sources of the wide gains in output experienced in the period from the end of the war to the mid-sixties. These increases in potential production simply were not matched by increases in demand adequate to maintain steady full employment.
Except for the recession years of 1949, 1954, and 1958, the rate of economic growth exceeded the rate of productivity increase. However, in the late 1950s productivity and labor force were increasing more rapidly than usual, while the growth of output was slower than usual. This accounted for the change in employment rates.
But if part of the national purpose is to reduce and contain unemployment, arithmetic is not enough. We must know which of the basic factors we can control and which we wish to control. Unemployment would have risen more slowly or fallen more rapidly if productivity had increased more slowly, or the labor force had increased more slowly, or the hours of work had fallen more steeply, or total output had grown more rapidly. These are not independent factors, however, and a change in any of them might have caused change in the others.
A society can choose to reduce the growth of productivity, and it can probably find ways to frustrate its own creativity. However, while a reduction in the growth of productivity at the expense of potential output might result in higher employment in the short run, the long-run effect on the national interest would be disastrous.
We must also give consideration to the fact that hidden beneath national averages is continuous movement into, out of, between, and within labor markets. For example, 15 years ago, the average number of persons in the labor force was 74 million, with about 70 million employed and 3.9 million unemployed. Yet 14 million experienced some term of unemployment in that year. Some were new entrants to the labor force; others were laid off temporarily, the remainders were those who were permanently or indefinitely severed from their jobs. Thus, the average number unemployed during a year understates the actual volume of involuntary-displacement that occurs.
High unemployment is not an inevitable result of the pace of technological change but the consequence of passive public policy. We can anticipate a moderate increase in the labor force accompanied by a slow and irregular decline in hours or work. It follows that the output of the economy—and the aggregate demand to buy it—must grow by more than 4 percent a year just to prevent the unemployment rate from rising, and by even more if the unemployment rate is to fail further. Yet our economy has seldom, if ever, grown at a rate greater than 3.5 percent for any extended length of time.
We have no cause for complacency. Positive fiscal, monetary, and man power policies will needed in the future. [br] According to the passage, the rate of employment can be expected to rise when ______.
选项
A、productivity rises at the same rate as growth of the labor force
B、productivity and labor force increase at a greater rate than output
C、output exceeds productivity
D、rate of economic growth is less than the number of man hours required
答案
C
解析
从第二段可以得出结论,其他答案与事实不相符。
转载请注明原文地址:http://tihaiku.com/zcyy/4036451.html
相关试题推荐
Changesinthevolumeofunemploymentaregovernedbythreefundamentalforce
Changesinthevolumeofunemploymentaregovernedbythreefundamentalforce
She______thehighunemploymentfiguresasevidenceofthefailureofthegover
Thefull______ofchangesincomputertechnologywillbefeltwithinthenextf
Theyearsbetween1870and1895broughtenormouschangestothetheaterint
Theyearsbetween1870and1895broughtenormouschangestothetheaterint
Scholarsmaintainthatsocialdevelopmentcaneasily____languagechanges.A、bring
She____thehighunemploymentfiguresasevidenceofthefailureofthegovernmen
Butweneedtogofurther.Wemustasksomefundamentalquestionsaboutthefutu
Securityandcommodityexchangesaretradingpostswherepeoplemeetwhowis
随机试题
LiPinandIare______.[br]LiPinis______.A、ateacherB、astudentC、apolic
励磁涌流的鉴别方法可分为频域特征鉴别和时域特征鉴别。()
A.A B. C. D.
以下药物中,是抗肾上腺素能药的是A.新斯的明 B.妥拉苏林 C.毛果芸香碱
根据中国证券投资基金业协会的分类标准,与企业非公开交易私人股权投资相关的基金类型
麻黄的发汗作用的主要机制是A.阻碍汗腺导管对钠离子的重吸收 B.兴奋α受体
关于工程项目特点的说法,正确的是()。A.工程项目的安全、质量、进度和费用目标可
一天中午,八年级的一批孩子正在操场上打篮球,战况“激烈”。学生Z和学生C从人群中
tRNA中与氨基酸结合的化学键是 A.氢键B.酯键C.肽键D.3',5'
共用题干 女,25岁。左耳垂下有时大时小的肿块6年,无自觉症状。检查见:耳垂下
最新回复
(
0
)